Quantitative easing and ‘loose’ monetary policy have not been successful in boosting UK export performance.
Craig Berry is a reseach fellow at the Sheffield Political Economy Research Institute and Scott Lavery is a doctoral researcher at the Sheffield Political Economy Research Institute
One of the professed goals of the coalition has been to ‘rebalance’ the UK economy away from debt-fuelled domestic consumption and into export-led growth, supported by increased investment in manufacturing.
There is growing evidence, however, that in spite of a recent increase in growth and employment, the government is not delivering what was promised. Rates of investment remain low, household debt is rising once again, and pay in manufacturing continues to slip behind financial services.
It didn’t have to be like this. Indeed, in many ways the post-2008 context has provided the ideal circumstances to re-orientate the British growth model towards tradable sectors such as manufacturing – primarily because sterling has deteriorated in value (at least partly by design). Research released by the Sheffield Political Economy Research Institute today, however, demonstrates a spectacular (and, in the postwar era, unprecedented) failure in this regard.
The report shows that, partly as a result of the policy of ‘quantitative easing’, sterling has undergone a significant depreciation over the past few years. Normally, this would result in a significant improvement of the trade balance.
This is because when a currency is devalued export goods become cheaper abroad, giving the exporters an advantage against competitors. Conversely, devaluation makes it more expensive to import goods (with a by-product of boosting domestic production). This should lead to an overall improvement in the balance of trade – the difference between goods and services which a country imports and exports.
If we look back on previous depreciations of the pound, we can see that this indeed did take place. For example, in 1976, sterling depreciated by 19.2 per cent against the dollar and 25 per cent against the Deutschemark in advance of ‘the IMF crisis’. In the following two years, the UK trade balance improved by an annual average of 161 per cent, followed by 153 per cent for the subsequent two years.
These changes in the trade balance represented a significant improvement on the trend evident in the four years prior to depreciation.
Similarly in the early 1990s, following the UK’s withdrawal from the European Exchange Rate Mechanism, the pound again depreciated against the Deutschemark by 15.4 per cent and 10.9 per cent against the dollar.
In the following two years, the UK trade balance improved by an annual average of 162 per cent, followed by 96 per cent for the subsequent two years.
One might expect that a comparable devaluation in 2008 would yield a similar improvement in the balance of trade. However, SPERI’s research demonstrates that in spite of a large sterling depreciation throughout the financial crisis of 2008 – of 15.4 per cent against the euro and 24.4 per cent against the dollar – we have not seen a marked improvement in the country’s trade balance.
Indeed, the UK trade balance deteriorated by an annual average of 6 per cent in the two years following devaluation, followed by 8 per cent for the subsequent two years.
This suggests that the problems facing the British economy are deeply entrenched.
Some commentators would point to difficulties in the Eurozone as a key factor explaining the absence of an improvement to the British balance of trade in spite of a favourable currency position. The euro has depreciated in value, and aggregate demand is considerably constrained across Europe.
Since a large proportion of our exports go to European markets, some would claim that it should come as little surprise that devaluation has not resulted in a turnaround in our trade position.
However, two points can be made against this argument. Firstly, despite some signs of competitive devaluation, sterling has remained under-valued against the euro, such that by the end of 2013 sterling was still 15.8 per cent down against the euro compared to its value in 2007. While both currencies have simultaneously depreciated, institutional and political constraints have prevented the Eurozone countries from engaging in a comparable devaluation to that of the UK.
Secondly, the UK’s failure to benefit from devaluation is in part due to its over-reliance on exporting business and financial services to Europe. If the ambition of export-led growth is to be achieved, it clearly requires a diversification of the UK export base, not least a resurgence in manufacturing exports.
In this regard, the UK compares unfavourably when we contrast its export performance with leading economies from the continent.
For example, partly as a response to deflation in the Eurozone, Germany has been re-orientating its exports towards emerging markets, particularly China. The UK, on the other hand, has not managed any such shift: we continue to export more to the crisis-afflicted ‘PIIGS’ countries than to all of the BRICs combined.
Depreciation could have aided a significant re-orientation towards these emerging markets, but the underlying weakness of the UK manufacturing base has proved to be a significant handicap.
We can conclude that quantitative easing and ‘loose’ monetary policy have not been successful in boosting UK export performance. Rather than helping to address the trade deficit, the policy has merely served to boost asset-prices and pump liquidity into a financial system which continues to withhold investment from the real economy.
Improving the trade balance will require more than central bank mandated asset-price inflation. We need to go beyond monetary policy and think through which institutional and political changes are needed to reverse the decline of UK manufacturing and the balance of trade problems which goes with it.
2 Responses to “Britain’s trade deficit persists in spite of sterling devaluation”
George Hallam
An excellent piece of work.
I agree that “the UK’s failure to benefit from devaluation is in part due to its over-reliance on exporting business and financial services to Europe. ”
However, I’m not so sure about your next sentence:
“If the ambition of export-led growth is to be achieved, it clearly requires a diversification of the UK export base, not least a resurgence in manufacturing exports.”
This begs the question that we need “export-led growth”.
A resurgence in manufacturing exports would help the balance of payments but it would not generate enough jobs to have much impact on unemployment. This is because the only areas where British manufacturing is likely to be competitive are those involving hi-tech processes. These are not labour intensive.
If we want to tackle mass unemployment, especially mass youth unemployment, the we need to develop more mundane, intermediate and low-tech industries. This suggests that import substitution is a more realistic goal.
the UK’s failure to benefit from devaluation is in part due to its over-reliance on exporting business and financial services to Europe. If the ambition of export-led growth is to be achieved, it clearly requires a diversification of the UK export base, not least a resurgence in manufacturing exports.
Peter Martin
The link between the external (trade) deficit and the budget deficit is not well understood but it’s not too difficult to explain.
For an net importing country, import payments drain money from the economy. The money is then retrieved by selling Treasury securities on the international market, and the proceeds recycled into the economy by budget deficit spending.
I would argue that all seems to work and should be left well alone.
However, if any Government were serious about “balancing its books” and eliminating both the internal and external deficit it should phase out the sale of Treasury securities.
It would probably mean a much lower pound. But if that’s what the UK electorate want and are happy with the prospect of petrol at £2 per litre then fine. Let’s go ahead.