Ed Miliband's pledge to "strengthen" the minimum wage in certain sectors is a step in the right direction, but it's not the most effective way to reduce inequality.
By John Hendy QC, chair of the Institute of Employment Rights, and professor Keith Ewing, president of the Institute of Employment Rights
Ed Miliband’s pledge to “strengthen” the minimum wage in certain sectors is a step in the right direction, both for workers and the economy. But it’s not the most effective way to reduce income inequality or reverse the damage done by the coalition’s cuts.
The main justification for austerity has been that there is a structural deficit in the finances of government that must be reduced. That the policies of austerity have in fact increased the deficit came as a surprise to no-one. Indeed, austerity could have had no other consequence.
The real driver for austerity is the desire to increase the share of the national economy consisting of profits and decrease the share consisting of wages. To that end austerity has been a resounding success.
The consequence of driving down the real value of wages is not just a painful cut in the standard of living of most people (so enhancing life for the rich). It has also depressed demand causing the loss of jobs and tax revenue and making the UK one of the worst performing economies in Europe.
Britain is now as unequal as it was at the end of the nineteenth century with all the repulsive consequences: unequal life expectancies, differential physical and mental health, lack of social mobility, unemployment, drugs, crime, hopelessness – and so on.
Obviously the share of the national cake occupied by wages must increase if any way is to be found out of the spiral of decline in Britain. It was once taken for granted that this would be achieved through the negotiation of pay and conditions between trade unions and employers – a process called collective bargaining. In our book Reconstruction after the crisis: a manifesto for collective bargaining, we make the case for the restoration of sectoral collective bargaining – that is collective bargaining on an industry by industry basis.
Collective bargaining of this kind was the policy of government for 75 years until Mrs Thatcher. It was the principal mechanism adopted in Britain and abroad to increase wages, stimulate demand and reinvigorate the economy to end the depression of the 1930s. The same remedy could be applied to the current crisis.
The reversal of government policy from 1980 onwards has caused collective bargaining coverage in Britain to plummet from protecting 82 per cent of workers in 1980 to 23 per cent today (and falling). Labour’s statutory recognition procedure had negligible effect. In western and northern Europe the average coverage remains at around 80 per cent (though, as we show in the book, in the name of austerity, collective bargaining is being undermined elsewhere in Europe).
The restoration of collective bargaining goes beyond stimulation of the economy. The loss of its protection has never been felt more keenly than now with a million people on zero-hours contracts, permanent full-timers being substituted by temporary and agency workers, 3 million being denied protection from unfair dismissal by the increase in the qualifying period, and all 29 million workers finding their way to an employment tribunal restricted by a fees hike.
Collective bargaining is the only way of giving workers an effective voice and power to prevent injustice in the workplace.
But there is also a legal imperative that underpins the economic and social case to rebuild the wasteland of collective bargaining.
Whether the government likes it or not, the UK (like other countries) has obligations to promote collective bargaining under international treaties signed by both Labour and Tory ministers since the end of the Second World War.
The failure over the last 30 years to comply with its international legal obligations has made the UK a repeated international law breaker, as the international bodies have consistently found.
A fresh start is required and a much more ambitious collective bargaining strategy, based on what we once had and what successful European economies still have.
We propose multi-employer agreements that apply throughout each industrial sector, laying down terms and conditions that apply to every worker, whether or not their employer recognises a union. Enterprise level bargaining can still take place but on the basic floor established by the sectoral collective agreement.
The sceptics will say that it is all too difficult. But we have done it before, in the 1930s when wise minds realised that the crisis of the time could be solved only by raising wages, and that the only way to raise wages was to strengthen the collective bargaining structures first established by Parliament during the First World War to deal with the problems of reconstruction.
To achieve it will require the same commitment to the use of state resources today as it did then, most notably a commitment to create the structures within which collective bargaining takes place, to ensure that employers take part, and that the terms of collective agreements are observed. It is a big challenge. But there really is no alternative.
2 Responses to “A raise in minimum wage is welcome, but it’s not the best we can do”
Bob
Could you tell us which international legal obligations and from which international treaties (including relevant articles)?
Institute of Employment Rights
There are a large number, but here are a few: The UN Declaration of Human Rights (Art 23 (4)), the International Covenant on Civil and Political Rights (Art 22), International Covenant on Economic, Social and Cultural Rights (Art 8(1)(a) &(d)), ILO Declaration on Fundamental Principles and Rights at Work 1998, European Convention on Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms (Art 11), European Social Chapter (Art 6). Taken from the publication by Ewing and Hendy. Thanks for your questions.
The Institute of Employment Rights